To be able to edit code and run cells, you need to run the notebook yourself. Where would you like to run the notebook?

This notebook takes about 50 seconds to run.

In the cloud (experimental)

Binder is a free, open source service that runs scientific notebooks in the cloud! It will take a while, usually 2-7 minutes to get a session.

On your computer

(Recommended if you want to store your changes.)

  1. Download the notebook:
  2. Run Pluto

    (Also see: How to install Julia and Pluto)

  3. Open the notebook file

    Type the saved filename in the open box.

Frontmatter

If you are publishing this notebook on the web, you can set the parameters below to provide HTML metadata. This is useful for search engines and social media.

Author 1
👀 Reading hidden code
html"""
<picture>
<source srcset="https://gci.iscte-iul.pt/2022/identidade/files/brand_v2/escolas/rgb/ibs/en/horizontal/negative/rgb_ibs_en_horizontal_negative.png" media="(prefers-color-scheme: dark)" width="240px!important" style="float:right;">
<img src="https://gci.iscte-iul.pt/2022/identidade/files/brand_v2/escolas/rgb/ibs/en/horizontal/main/rgb_ibs_en_horizontal_main.png" width="240px" style="float:right;">
</picture>
"""
25.6 μs

Week 10 - Macroeconomic Policy and Extreme Shocks

Exercises

Macroeconomics, ISCTE-IUL

👀 Reading hidden code
4.1 ms

Vivaldo Mendes, Ricardo Gouveia-Mendes, Luís Clemente-Casinhas

May 2005

👀 Reading hidden code
263 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
3.1 ms

Packages used in this notebook

👀 Reading hidden code
174 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
begin
using HypertextLiteral
: @htl, @htl_str
, PlutoUI, PlutoPlotly, StatsBase, ShiftedArrays
using CSV, DataFrames, Dates, PeriodicalDates, NLsolve
end
1.2 s

Exercise 1. The Fed's Dual Mandate (again)

👀 Reading hidden code
183 μs

One of the Fed branches—the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago—published an image that explains the Fed's double mandate in a very simple way. The figure can be found below, taken from here.

👀 Reading hidden code
8.4 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
144 μs

👉 a) In your own words, what are the two fundamental goals of the Fed over time?

👀 Reading hidden code
187 μs

Answer (a)

The two fundamental goals of the Fed over time are: π=πT=2%, and U=Un.

👀 Reading hidden code
8.9 ms

👉 b) Given what you have studied in this course, suppose the natural unemployment (Un) rate is 4%, and the current level of unemployment is U=6%. What would we expect the Fed's reaction would be?

👀 Reading hidden code
3.1 ms

Answer (b)

As U>Un, we would expect the Fed to reduce nominal interest rates, to stimulate aggregate demand, increase GDP, and reduce unemployment.

👀 Reading hidden code
154 μs

👉 c) Given what you have studied in this course, suppose the rate of inflation (π) is 5%, while the target rate of inflation is (πT) is 2%. What would we expect the Fed's reaction would be?

👀 Reading hidden code
246 μs

Answer (c)

As π>πT, we would expect the Fed to increase nominal interest rates, reduce aggregate demand, reduce GDP, and bring inflation down to its target level.

👀 Reading hidden code
149 μs

👉 d) Suppose that the two cases above co-exist simultaneously. What should the Fed do in this case? Give up one of them, give up both, or balance both in some way?

👀 Reading hidden code
168 μs

Answer (d)

If the two cases co-occur, the Fed should balance the two goals over time. In the past, the Fed has usually given higher priority to controlling inflation than to reducing unemployment. Still, that decision is totally dependent on the composition of the Fed's board at each particular period.

👀 Reading hidden code
184 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
240 μs

Exercise 2. Unemployment and recessions

👀 Reading hidden code
155 μs

The following figure presents the evolution of the unemployment rate (UR) and the Fed Funds Rate (FFR) for the US economy from the mid 1960s to 2024.

👀 Reading hidden code
172 μs
197019801990200020102020051015
URFFRUnemployment Rate (UR) and the Fed Funds Rate (FFR)DatePercentageShaded bars: NBER recessions
👀 Reading hidden code
3.6 s

👉 a) What happens to the unemployment rate in every single recession in this period? Why?

👀 Reading hidden code
196 μs

Answer (a)

  1. In all recessions, the unemployment rate increases significantly.

  2. Why? Because a recession is defined as a substantial reduction in GDP below Potential GDP, which leads to a significant decrease in employment and a consequent increase in the unemployment rate.

👀 Reading hidden code
251 μs

👉 b) What happens to the Fed Funds Rate in every single recession in this period? Why?

👀 Reading hidden code
219 μs

Answer (b)

  1. In all recessions, the Fed Funds Rate decreases significantly.

  2. Why? A recession leads to a substantial increase in the unemployment rate, and one of the Fed's main goals is to "support maximum employment". Therefore, the Fed has to reduce interest rates to stimulate demand, which in turn will increase GDP and employment.

👀 Reading hidden code
175 μs

👉 c) The following figure presents a cross-plot between the US's unemployment and Fed Funds rates between 1955 and 2024, and the correlation coefficient between these two variables is close to zero (0.063). Given this evidence and the theory that we have studied, in your opinion, what is the correct remark: (i) there is no causality between these two macroeconomic variables; (ii) if the Fed reduces the FFR, the unemployment rate goes up; (iii) if unemployment is very high, it has to come down, and the Fed is forced to reduce the FFR.

👀 Reading hidden code
244 μs
0510152034567891011
Unemployment rate vs. Fed Funds Rate (US: 1955-2024)Fed Funds Rate (FFR)Unemployment rate (UR)
👀 Reading hidden code
123 ms

Answer (c)

The correct remark is (iii).

👀 Reading hidden code
146 μs

👉 d) Are there other major macroeconomic variables that directly affect the decision of the Fed regarding the FFR? If yes, what are they?

👀 Reading hidden code
213 μs

Note

The main reason macroeconomic theory is helpful is that it prevents us from making stupid mistakes that are masked as irrefutable observations. It is easy to see that in the plot above, there is no significant correlation between these two macroeconomic aggregates. Therefore, we would be inclined to prematurely conclude that the Fed does not react to unemployment. Why is this speedy reasoning incorrect?

👀 Reading hidden code
161 μs

Answer (d)

As the Fed has a "dual mandate" with the goals of maximum employment and stable prices, the other major macroeconomic variable affecting the Fed's decisions regarding the FFR is the inflation rate. That is why we do not see a clear causality between the FFR and the unemployment rate in the plot above, as there is another major player in this game, which is not present in that figure.

👀 Reading hidden code
19.0 ms

👀 Reading hidden code
140 μs

Exercise 3. Inflation targeting

👀 Reading hidden code
235 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
31.0 μs

On 8 July 2021, the European Central Bank (ECB) announced a revision of its monetary policy strategy for the first time since its creation in 1998. From the article above in the Financial Times, one can read:

"The central bank said its new target of 2 per cent was symmetric, “meaning negative and positive deviations of inflation from the target are equally undesirable”. The new target is a medium-term objective with flexibility to fluctuate in either direction in the short term [and] said it could tolerate temporary moves beyond that point, in a shift that gives policymakers flexibility to keep interest rates at historic lows for longer”.

👉 a) Figure 1 plots the data about inflation in the EuroZone (EZ) and Portugal since 1998. Why do you think the ECB stresses "the symmetric deviations of inflation from the target"?

👀 Reading hidden code
263 μs
20002005201020152020−2−1012345
EuroZonePortugalFig 1. Inflation in the EuroZone and PortugalMonthly obervationsPercentage pointsTarget inflation rate (2%)
👀 Reading hidden code
517 ms

Answer (a)

The ECB stresses "the symmetric deviations of inflation from the target" to clarify that it will not tolerate inflation rates below 2%, no matter how low and stable they may be. Inflation above target and below target should be treated similarly.

👀 Reading hidden code
175 μs

👉 b) Why do you think the article stresses "...in a shift that gives policymakers flexibility to keep interest rates at historic lows for longer”?

👀 Reading hidden code
162 μs

Answer (b)

Usually, using the target as a "ceiling" leads to a situation where inflation is too low. In the summer of 2021, the ECB feared deflation and wanted to increase inflation to the 2% target level. Changing the strategy to "symmetric deviations" would lead to higher inflation, requiring keeping interest rates very low for an extended period.

👀 Reading hidden code
155 μs

👉 c) Figure 2 below shows the inflation deviations from its target, according to the old strategy (we will call it "Loss1"), while Figure 3 displays the deviations according to the new strategy ("Loss2").

👀 Reading hidden code
152 μs

Note

If central banks do not achieve the 2% target level for inflation, they do their job poorly. They will be penalized sooner or later because the economy (and society) suffers a Loss of welfare from those deviations. The greater the deviations, the greater will be Loss society will bear.

👀 Reading hidden code
147 μs
2000200520102015202000.511.522.533.542000200520102015202000.511.522.533.54
EuroZonePortugalEuroZonePortugalMonthly observationsMonthly observationsPercentage pointsPercentage pointsFig 2. Positive Deviations from TargetFig 3. Positive & Negative Deviations from Target
👀 Reading hidden code
653 ms
Loss to societymeanminmedianmaxstandard dev.
Euro Zone (Ceiling)0.17990.00.02.10.3579
Euro Zone (True target)0.75680.00.62.60.6422
Portugal (Ceiling)0.50810.00.03.10.7180
Portugal (True target)1.20810.01.23.80.8148
👀 Reading hidden code
75.0 ms

Answer (c)

In the previous figure, we can easily observe why the central bank's loss function is dramatically affected by having only positive deviations from the target as its argument or by having both positive and negative deviations as arguments. The first case can be written in the following way:

Loss={ππT    ,π>πT0  , otherwise

while the second case has to be written using the absolute value operator:

Loss=|ππT|

The left-hand panel (Fig. 2) shows the first case. The right-hand side panel (Fig. 3) shows the second case; the losses are significantly much more significant than those in the left panel. This fact is the fundamental reason the ECB has decided to produce a drastic reform in its monetary policy strategy after more than twenty years since it started to operate.

The means of the Loss function according to each rule (the old strategy, which considered only positive deviations from the target, and the new strategy, which includes both positive and negative deviations) are presented in the following table.

 Table 1: Mean of the Loss function  Positive deviations  Both deviations  Eurozone 0.17990.7568 Portugal 0.50811.2081

👀 Reading hidden code
246 μs

👉 d) If you had responsibilities as a watchdog of the European Central Bank (for example, as a member of the European Parliament), and the ECB President argued that they had been doing a good job because the Loss to society was very small according to the old strategy, what would your position be?

👀 Reading hidden code
184 μs

Answer (d)

I would say that the ECB President was trying to mislead the public because Figure 3, not Figure 2, gives the true cost (loss) to society. In the case of the Eurozone as a whole, the actual Loss (Figure 3) is 4.2 times higher than the Loss presented by the old strategy in Figure 2 (0.757/0.18=4.2), and I would argue that the ECB had to change its approach by considering symmetric deviations instead of positive deviations only.

👀 Reading hidden code
191 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
133 μs

Exercise 4. The Textbook Rule (MP curve)

👀 Reading hidden code
146 μs

In week 5 we introduced the MP curve into our framework:

(1)r=r+λπ

where r stands for the real interest rate, π for the inflation rate, r as the natural real interest rate, and λ is a parameter that shows how much central banks dislike inflation. This curve was supposed to express the way the central bank sets the nominal interest rate by using this curve in connection with the Fisher equation that we studied in week 3:

(2)i=r+π

where i is the nominal interest rate. By inserting eq. (1) into eq. (2), we get the nominal interest rate that the central bank should set:

(3)i=r+(1+λ)π

Interestingly, we can easily check whether a central bank (like the Fed) followed such a rule (MP curve) to set its nominal interest rates. We can collect data on i, on π, give reasonable values for r and λ, and see if the Fed followed this rule. Let us assume that r=2% and λ=0.5. The data is in the file "Taylor.csv" and can be found in the table below.

👀 Reading hidden code
373 μs
QuartersPotGDPGDPCPIFFR
DateFloat64Float64Float64Float64
1
1960-01-01
3491.81
3517.18
1.4
3.93
2
1960-04-01
3527.85
3498.25
1.8
3.7
3
1960-07-01
3563.32
3515.39
1.4
2.94
4
1960-10-01
3597.51
3470.28
1.4
2.3
5
1961-01-01
3631.1
3493.7
1.5
2.0
6
1961-04-01
3662.76
3553.02
0.9
1.73
7
1961-07-01
3695.59
3621.25
1.2
1.68
8
1961-10-01
3729.38
3692.29
0.7
2.4
9
1962-01-01
3765.8
3758.15
0.9
2.46
10
1962-04-01
3805.31
3792.15
1.3
2.61
more
259
2024-07-01
22800.6
23386.2
2.6
5.26
👀 Reading hidden code
2.3 s
begin
r̄ = 2 ; λ = 0.5 # Exogenous variables & parameters
π = Rules_Data.CPI ; i = Rules_Data.FFR # Data about π and i
textbook_rule = r̄ .+ (1.0 .+ λ) .* π # the textbook rule
end;
👀 Reading hidden code
56.3 ms

👉 a) In the figures below, we plot the Federal Funds Rate (the FFR, our i in the equations above) and its value according to the rule presented by the textbook. Do you think the textbook rule does an excellent job of explaining the decisions of the Fed regarding interest rates?

👀 Reading hidden code
190 μs

Answer (a)

No, it does not. The gaps between what the textbook rule predicts and what the Fed has done (FFR) are huge, sometimes on the verge of 10 or even 15 percentage points.

👀 Reading hidden code
140 μs
196019701980199020002010202005101520251960197019801990200020102020051015
Textbook RuleFFRTextbook rule versus the Federal Funds RateTextbook rule minus the Federal Funds Rate
👀 Reading hidden code
534 ms

👉 b) Given what we discussed in Exercise 1, in your opinion, why does the textbook rule perform so poorly in the case of the Fed?

👀 Reading hidden code
164 μs

Answer (b)

It performs exceptionally poorly because the Fed sets nominal interest rates considering the natural real interest rate and the inflation rate (as the textbook does), but it also takes into account what happens to unemployment (which is not included in the textbook rule for simplicity).

👀 Reading hidden code
175 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
133 μs

Exercise 5. The Taylor rule

👀 Reading hidden code
149 μs

In 1993, John Taylor from Stanford University presented a monetary policy rule that became very famous. He conjectured that the Fed, according to its dual mandate, should set nominal interest rates according to the equation:

(Taylor Rule)i=r¯+π+λππgap+λyYgap

where πgap=ππT is the inflation gap between the actual rate of inflation and the target inflation rate, while Ygap=YYPYP is the output gap in percentage units. Taylor suggested that the weights for the inflation gap and the output gap should be similar (λπ=λy=0.5), and the natural real interest rate should be r=2%.

We will apply the same procedure as in the previous exercise. Let us insert the data into the notebook:

👀 Reading hidden code
342 μs
begin
λ_π = 0.5 ; λ_y = 0.5 ; πᵀ = 2.0 # Exogenous variables & parameters specific to this rule
Y = Rules_Data.GDP ; Yᴾ = Rules_Data.PotGDP # Data about Y, Yᴾ (π and i already inserted in the previous exercise)

Taylor_rule = r̄ .+ π .+ λ_π .* (π .- πᵀ) .+ λ_y .* (100 .* ((Y .- Yᴾ) ./ Yᴾ)) # The Taylor rule

# the term 100 above is used to express the output gap in percentage points (for example, 2pp instead of 0.02)

end;
👀 Reading hidden code
217 ms

👉 a) In the figure below, we compare what the Taylor Rule predicts against the nominal interest rate that the Fed actually sets (the FFR). Does this rule better explain the Fed's decisions concerning the Fed Funds Rate than the textbook rule?

👀 Reading hidden code
192 μs
1960197019801990200020102020−5051015201960197019801990200020102020−50510
Taylor RuleFFRTaylor rule versus the Federal Funds RateTaylor rule minus the Federal Funds Rate
👀 Reading hidden code
384 μs

Answer (a)

The deviations of the FFR from the values given by the Taylor rule are much smaller than in the previous rule (the textbook rule). Therefore, the Taylor rule performs better than the previous one.

👀 Reading hidden code
138 μs

👉 b) Can you provide evidence that having a Taylor Rule in autopilot may lead to extreme "punishments" for the economy? Examples where applying this rule would lead to unbearable economic situations.

👀 Reading hidden code
262 μs

Answer (b)

There have been several periods when the Fed Funds Rate (FFR) was systematically much lower (or much higher) than the value given by the Taylor rule. We provide some examples that look awkward from an economic point of view:

  1. In the early 1980s, the Taylor rule suggests that the Fed should have had interest rates much lower than it did. For example, in July 1983, the FFR was 7.14 percentage points higher than as indicated by the Taylor rule.

  2. In July 2009, at the center of the Great Recession, while the Fed reduced the FFR to zero, the Taylor rule indicates that the Fed should have reduced those rates to 4.1%. We do not have any evidence that any central bank has ever decreased nominal interest rates to such negative values.

  3. Another awkward example is what the Taylor rule suggests the Fed should have done recently. In April 2022, the Fed had the FFR at 0.77%, while this rule indicates that it should have been at 13.13%. Notice that inflation has recently come down to 2%, but the FFR never overcame the mark of 5.5%.

👀 Reading hidden code
213 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
118 μs

Exercise 6. A Good Rule: the "First-Difference" rule

👀 Reading hidden code
158 μs

The Taylor rule is one of the rules the Fed uses when deciding to change (or maintain) nominal interest rates, and, as we saw in the previous exercise, it does not perform very well. That is why the Fed uses also other rules. In this website Policy Rules and How Policymakers Use Them, the Fed describes five different rules that it usually takes into consideration in its decision-making process. One of them is called "The First-Difference" rule and is expressed as follows:

it=FFRt1+0.1(πtπT)+0.1(ytyt4)

where FFRt1 denotes the actual federal funds rate for quarter t1, yt is the natural logarithm of real GDP in quarter t, and yt4 is the natural logarithm of real GDP in quarter t4.

👀 Reading hidden code
453 μs

👉 a) In the figure below, we plot the First-Difference rule and the actual Fed Funds Rate. Considering the gaps between what the rule predicts and the actual Fed Funds Rate, does this new rule perform better or worse than the Taylor rule seen in the previous exercise?

👀 Reading hidden code
173 μs
1960197019801990200020102020051015197019801990200020102020−4−2024
First-Difference RuleFFRThe First-Difference rule versus the Federal Funds RateThe First-Difference rule minus the Federal Funds Rate
👀 Reading hidden code
1.6 ms

Answer (a)

The First-Difference rule performs much better than the Taylor rule, for two reasons: (i) the gaps between what the rule predicts and the actual Fed Funds Rate are much smaller than in the case of the Taylor rule, and (ii) the First-Difference rule does not lead to extremely abnormal outcomes like the Taylor rule does (e.g., –3% in April 2020, and +13.4% in April 2022).

👀 Reading hidden code
185 μs

👉 b) What happens when extreme events knock-on economic activity when compared to the Taylor rule? For example, what happened during the Great Recession of 2008-2010, the Covid pandemic in 2020, or the recent rampant inflation in 2022/2023?

👀 Reading hidden code
616 μs

Answer (b)

When the economy faces extreme events like those mentioned in the question above, this rule avoids the dramatic changes in the Fed Funds Rate as those that arise from the Taylor rule. For example, consider what happened in July 2009 (in the middle of the Great Recession): the Taylor rule indicated that the Fed should have reduced the Fed Funds Rate to 4.2% (a value that looks impossible to implement), while the First-Difference rule gives a value of 0.27%, which is a much more acceptable value for such a rate. The same reasoning can be applied to the other two extreme events.

👀 Reading hidden code
335 μs

👉 c) Given the evidence in the three rules that we have been discussing, are monetary policy rules useless?

👀 Reading hidden code
170 μs

Answer (c)

Bad rules are useless, but good rules are beneficial because if the central bank follows good rules when conducting monetary policy, there will be less uncertainty in the economy. This less uncertainty arises because private agents know that the central bank has a rule, a sound/credible rule, has a commitment to follow such rule, and they will react to the shocks that hit the economy in accordance with the behavior of the central bank. Private agents know what to expect from the central bank, and this reduces uncertainty.

👀 Reading hidden code
94.5 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
126 μs

Exercise 7. The Volcker Disinflation, 1980–1986

👀 Reading hidden code
146 μs

On page 309 in the textbook:

"When Paul Volcker became the chairman of the Federal Reserve in August 1979, inflation had spun out of control, and the inflation rate exceeded 10%. Volcker was determined to get inflation down. By early 1981, the Federal Reserve had raised the federal funds rate to over 20%, which led to a sharp increase in real interest rates. Volcker successfully brought inflation down, with the inflation rate falling from 13.5% in 1980 to 1.9% in 1986. The decline in inflation came at a high cost: the economy experienced the worst recession up to that time since World War II, with the unemployment rate soaring to 9.7% in 1982."

In the two figures below, we provide further context for this period by providing evidence about the inflation rate (we use headline inflation in this exercise), the Fed Funds Rate (FFR), and the growth rate of international oil prices.

👀 Reading hidden code
268 μs
197619781980198219841986198819905101520
InflationFFRHeadline Inflation and FFR (1975-1990)DateValuesVolcker tenure as Fed's Chair
👀 Reading hidden code
270 ms
197619781980198219841986198819902468101214−50050100150
InflationOil prices growthHeadline Inflation vs Growth Rate of Oil Prices (1975-1990)DateInflation (Left)Grwoth of Oil Prices (Right)Volcker tenure as Fed's Chair
👀 Reading hidden code
47.8 ms

👉 (a) What was the Volcker disinflation?

👀 Reading hidden code
190 μs

Answer (a)

Volcker disinflation occurred during the 1980s, a period of unprecedentedly high inflation in the US and all Western economies. The Fed conducted a highly aggressive monetary policy, leading to an abrupt and brutal increase in real interest rates to reduce high inflation figures.

👀 Reading hidden code
142 μs

👉 (b) By inspecting the two figures above, which cover the period of the Volcker disinflation, how does the behavior of the Fed Funds Rate and international oil prices affect the US economy?

👀 Reading hidden code
223 μs

Answer (b)

  1. The real interest rate (FFR minus Inflation) increased dramatically in the 1980s compared to previous decades. For example, in June 1981, it was higher than 9% (19.1%-9.7%=9.4%). These huge real interest rates led to a massive decline in aggregate demand in the US economy, which was expected to lower inflation.

  2. The price of oil in international markets suffered a monumental decline throughout the 1980s. Notice that the annual growth rate of oil prices in April 1980 reached an astronomical figure of 149.2%. Still, it came down systematically over the decade, reaching a negative value of 57.6% in July 1986. Oil prices suffered a large collapse during the 1980s, significantly contributing to reducing inflation.

👀 Reading hidden code
353 μs

👉 (c) Can we explain that sharp decline in inflation in the 1980s using our AD/AS/MP model?**

👀 Reading hidden code
207 μs

Answer (c)

Yes, the AD/AS/MP framework can easily explain what happened to inflation in the US during the 1980s. This is why models are helpful.

  1. The Fed aggressively increased interest rates in the early 1980s. This increase shifted the MP curve to the left, leading to higher real interest rates for every level of inflation.

  2. In our model above, the shift in the MP curve forces the AD curve to move to the left, creating a recession and lower inflation. The economy will gradually recover, and the recession will gradually vanish while inflation comes down step by step.

  3. The process in (1) and (2) will significantly speed up if oil prices come down year after year, as they did in the 1980s. If oil prices go down, the AS curve will shift down (to the right), reducing inflation further and leading to higher GDP.

  4. At the end of this process, we have lower inflation and no recession. The economy had to pay a high price for reducing inflation from 14.6% (the pick of inflation in April 1980) to 1.7% in January 1987 (the bottom of inflation in the 1980s). This cost was a large recession and huge unemployment figures.

👀 Reading hidden code
206 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
129 μs

Exercise 8. Inflation and the Scariest Opinion of 2022

👀 Reading hidden code
142 μs

In the Wall Street Journal, Sept. 7, 2022, Jason Furman – a Professor at Harvard University and a former Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers of President Barack Obama – published an Op-Ed. that ran with the title "Inflation and the Scariest Economics Paper of 2022". The scariest paper can be found here and was written by two IMF economists and Larry Ball from John Hopkins University. The principal message from this paper was:

"To bring price increases down to 2%, we may need to tolerate unemployment of 6.5% for two years."

Earlier, on June 20 of the same year, another highly respected economist, Larry Summers, made the same point even more forcefully in a speech in London:

"We need five years of unemployment above 5% to contain inflation – in other words, we need two years of 7.5% unemployment, or five years of 6% unemployment, or one year of 10% unemployment." Bloomberg

Considering the evolution of inflation (CPI), unemployment (UR), and oil prices (Oil) in the US economy that is depicted in the figure below, answer the following questions:

👉 a) why do you think economists and policymakers were so worried about inflation in the middle of 2022?

👀 Reading hidden code
416 μs
2016201720182019202020212022202320240246810121420406080100120
CPIUROilThe Scary Paper and Some DataCPI and UR: percentage pointsOil price: dollars per barrel
👀 Reading hidden code
148 ms

Answer (a)

In the summer of 2022, US inflation reached close to 9%, the highest level since 1980.

Economists and policymakers feared that the Fed would be unable to contain inflation. If inflation continued to increase even further, people would start to doubt whether the Fed would be able to control inflation, high inflationary expectations would set in, and the situation in the late 1970s would come back to haunt us with unmanageable inflation.

👀 Reading hidden code
151 μs

👉 b) In the case of those two economists mentioned above, what was the reason (or factor) causing so much inflation in the US?

👀 Reading hidden code
148 μs

Answer (b)

For them, the main reason was that the US labor market was "too hot." By that, we mean a situation in which the actual unemployment rate (U) was much lower than the natural unemployment rate (Un). In their opinion, the only way to bring down inflation was to repeat Volcker's recipe from the early 1980s: a massive increase in interest rates, which would cause a recession and a large increase in unemployment. A recession and higher unemployment would bring down inflation.

👀 Reading hidden code
181 μs

👉 c) Given the evidence in the figure above, since June 2022, inflation has come down in the US, achieved without any significant increase in the unemployment rate. Were the two economists above correct in their recipe for the problem of controlling inflation?

👀 Reading hidden code
178 μs

Answer (c)

No, apparently, the problem was that the labor market was not "too hot" as they thought.

👀 Reading hidden code
143 μs

👉 d) Those two economists based their prescriptions on one fundamental diagnosis: rampant inflation resulted from a "too hot" labor market. By checking the figure above, can you see any connection between oil price increases and inflation?

👀 Reading hidden code
177 μs

Answer (d)

It is easy to see that a tremendous increase in oil prices was causing inflation, not a hot labor market.

In fact, it takes a simple number to refute their argument: when inflation started to increase (May 2020), the unemployment rate was 13.2%. How can such labor market conditions lead to a surge in inflation? From an economic point of view, it is irrational to conjecture that, at least in our societies.

To confirm the impact of oil prices on inflation, we need another simple number: when inflation started to increase (May 2020), oil prices were 28.56 dollars per barrel, and they jumped to 114.88 in June 2022, when inflation achieved its peak. Then oil prices started to come down, and so did inflation.

👀 Reading hidden code
174 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
559 μs

Exercise 9. Abenomics and Japanese deflation

👀 Reading hidden code
160 μs

In our classes, we discussed the terrible problem that deflation may bring to developed market economies. Japan is a classic example of a highly successful developed economy that was successful until the late 1990s but has fallen into a deflation trap since then.

The following figure presents Japan's inflation and unemployment evolution over the last four decades. Discounting the period of Abenomics — Shinzo Abe was the prime minister between 2013 and 2020 and was elected on the promise that he would take "all necessary and sufficient measures to ensure the country will eradicate deflation" — Japan has been stuck in deflation since the summer of 1998.

👉 a) Considering its target inflation rate of 2%, how frequently did Japan reach such a target since 1998-M07?

👀 Reading hidden code
247 μs
19911994199720002003200620092012201520182021−20246
URCPIInflation (CPI) and Unemployment (UR) Rates in Japan: 1991-2021Monthly observationsPercentage points1998-M07Shinzo Abe as prime-minister
👀 Reading hidden code
262 ms

Answer (a)

Very rarely. Discounting the Abenomics period, only during four months (June to September 2008) did Japan live with 2% or higher inflation.

👀 Reading hidden code
141 μs

👉 b) In normal conditions, if an economy suffers from very low inflation, it will experience high unemployment rates. This relationship is what the Phillips curve tells us. Can we observe this situation in Japan since 1998-M07?

👀 Reading hidden code
158 μs

Answer (b)

No, we can not observe such a relationship for Japan since 1998-M07. The Japanese economy has experienced very low unemployment during long deflationary periods.

👀 Reading hidden code
136 μs

👉 c) The unemployment rate in Japan is very low indeed. It is implausible that this rate can go lower than 2% or 3%. This information tells us something about Potential GDP. What is it?

👀 Reading hidden code
160 μs

Answer (c)

It tells us that real GDP must be close to the Potential GDP. If real GDP were much lower than Potential GDP, the unemployment rate had to be much higher than 3%, the rate it is experiencing now.

👀 Reading hidden code
152 μs

👉 d) Someone asks you to create a slogan to describe the Japanese experience above. What would you propose?

👀 Reading hidden code
181 μs

One possible answer (d)

"Living at potential, addicted to deflation"

👀 Reading hidden code
138 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
146 μs

Exercise 10. The Zero Lower Bound: a numerical exercise

👀 Reading hidden code
150 μs

Consider the four fundamental functions that allow us to analyze the entire functioning of the economy:

AD:Y=mAmϕ(r+λπ)AS:π=πe+γ(YYP)+ρMP:r=r+λπFisher Eq.:i=r+π

and the following information concerning exogenous variables and parameters:

A=7.6 , m=2.0 , ϕ=0.2 , r=2.0 , λ=0.5 , πe=2.0 , γ=4.5 , YP=14.0 , ρ=0.

First, we must pass the information about exogenous variables and parameters into the notebook:

👀 Reading hidden code
248 μs
begin
Ā3 = 7.6 ; λ3 = 0.5 ; m3 = 2.0 ; ϕ3 = 0.2; r̄3 = 2.0 # Demand-side parameters and exogenous variables
γ3 = 4.5 ; Yᴾ3 = 14.0 ; πᵉ3 = 2.0 ; ρ3 = 0.0 # Supply-side parameters and exogenous variables
end;
👀 Reading hidden code
29.1 μs

Note

This exercise continues the previous weeks' exercises by adding a new ingredient: the Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) on interest rates. As the impact of the ZLB will arrive from question (b) onwards, the answer to question (a) will already be given here because it follows the same steps as in previous weeks.

Note that to simplify things, we continue to use the same strategy as before: {πe,r,r,i,ρ} are rates and are measured in percentage points (e.g., 2.0 means 2.0%), while {Y,YP,A} are measured in trillion dollars. In the solutions below, to avoid doubt, we put the symbol % only at the final step of the solutions.

👀 Reading hidden code
186 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
138 μs

👉 a) Calculate the short-run equilibrium values for the inflation rate, the level of GDP, the real interest rate, and the nominal interest rate. The graphical representation of this equilibrium is displayed in Fig. 4 and 5.

👀 Reading hidden code
213 μs

Solution using NLsolve

👀 Reading hidden code
8.0 ms
begin
function my_model10_3!(F, v) # we name our model as model10_3
π = v[1] # variable 1 is π
Y = v[2] # variable 2 is Y
r = v[3] # variable 3 is r
i = v[4] # variable 4 is i
F[1] = m3 * Ā3 - m3 * ϕ3 * (r̄3 + λ3 * π) - Y # AD curve = 0
F[2] = πᵉ3 + γ3 * (Y - Yᴾ3) - π # AS curve = 0
F[3] = r̄3 + λ3 * π - r # MP curve = 0
F[4] = π + r - i # Fisher equation = 0
end

solution10_3 = nlsolve(my_model10_3!, [0.0; 0.0; 0.0; 0.0])
solution10_3.zero
end
👀 Reading hidden code
5.8 s

Answer (a)

We can summarize the initial equilibrium of the economy at point 1:

Y1=YP=14  , π1=2%  ,  r1=2%  ,  i1=5%.

👀 Reading hidden code
163 μs
122.533.544.5012345113.613.81414.214.4012345
MPEq1YpADASEq1Real interest rate (r)GDP trillion dollars (Y)Rate of inflation (π)Rate of inflation (π)Fig 4. MP CurveFig 5. Macroeconomic Equilibrium
👀 Reading hidden code
721 μs

Hint

The rate of inflation that corresponds to the ZLB is easy to obtain. We just have to recall that

πZL=r1+λ

👀 Reading hidden code
145 μs

👉 b) Calculate the inflation rate value that corresponds to the ZLB (Zero Lower Bound).

👀 Reading hidden code
157 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
60.2 μs

Answer (b)

As we know that

πZL=r1+λ

so (see cell below):

πZL=1.333.

👀 Reading hidden code
161 μs

👉 c) In Fig. 6 and 7, we represent the equilibrium associated with the AS/AD curves graphically (including the part related to the ZLB), and we do the same for the MP curve. Is the equilibrium in the ZLB?

👀 Reading hidden code
176 μs

Answer (c)

The equilibrium is not in the ZLB because the level of inflation is 2%, which is higher than the level of inflation that corresponds to the ZLB:

πZL=1.333%.

👀 Reading hidden code
145 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
131 μs

Exercise 11. A negative demand shock and the ZLB

👀 Reading hidden code
158 μs

Consider the same values as in the previous exercise. However, an external shock affects the Autonomous Demand, which decreases A by $0.2 trillion.

👉 a) The short-run equilibrium values for the inflation rate, the level of GDP, and the real interest rate are represented in Figs 8 and 9. What is the level of the nominal interest rate in this equilibrium?

👀 Reading hidden code
28.7 ms

Answer (a)

At point 2, we can summarize the new equilibrium of the economy by:

YPY2=13.7895 , π2=1.05263% , r2=2.5263% , i2=3.5789%.

So the level of the nominal interest rate in this equilibrium is i2=3.5789%.

👀 Reading hidden code
160 μs
211234−4−3−2−1012341213.51414.5−4−3−2−101234
Eq2Eq1MPMPzlZLBADADzlZLBYpASEq1Eq2Real interest rate (% points)GDP trillion dollars (Y)Rate of inflation (% points)Rate of inflation (% points)Fig 8. The MP Curve with a ZLBFig 9. The AD/AS Curves with a ZLB
👀 Reading hidden code
923 μs

👉 b) Is the economy in a recession, or in an economic boom? Justify.

👀 Reading hidden code
211 μs

Answer (b)

The economy moved from point 1 to point 2, and is now in recession, as YP=14>Y2=13.78.

👀 Reading hidden code
196 μs

👉 c) If there is no other demand or supply shock what will happen to the economy over time?

👀 Reading hidden code
224 μs

Answer (c)

The new equilibrium at point 2 is not a long-term equilibrium because the current level of GDP is below the Potential GDP. So the economy is in a recession, and inflation will gradually come down by the self-correcting market mechanism. This gradual process shifts the AS curve to the right until it reaches the vertical curve (Potential GDP). This process leads to point 3 (in the following figure), which is both a short and long-term equilibrium, as long as the central bank accepts this new inflation rate as the new target level for such rate.

There is still one crucial point. If the central bank does not accept a reduction in πT to 0%, it should have reacted with a more aggressive monetary policy at point 2. If the central bank had reduced the interest rate by far more than -0.474% (from 3% to 2.526%), the AD curve would have shifted to the right, and the initial shock could have been neutralized. Notice that if the central bank had chosen a more aggressive monetary policy, the MP function would have shifted to the left.

👀 Reading hidden code
288 μs

👉 d) What will be the new value of the long-run equilibrium inflation rate? What about the real and nominal interest rates?

👀 Reading hidden code
176 μs

Note

To answer question (d), we have to represent this new equilibrium graphically by using the slider self_correction7. By how much will inflation decline such that the new AS function will cross the YP curve at 0%? A quick inspection of the plots above will tell us that the self-correcting mechanism will force inflation to go down by 2 percentage points. We can call this mechanism by "self_correction".

👀 Reading hidden code
203 μs

self_correction7 =0.0

👀 Reading hidden code
451 ms
1231234−4−3−2−10123412313.51414.5−4−3−2−101234
Eq1Eq2Eq3MPMPzlZLBYpASAS2ADADzlZLBEq1Eq2Eq3Real interest rate (% points)GDP trillion dollars (Y)Rate of inflation (% points)Rate of inflation (% points)Fig 8. The MP Curve with a ZLBFig 9. The AD/AS Curves with a ZLB
👀 Reading hidden code
925 μs

Answer (d)

The new long term equilibrium at point 3 will be characterized by:

YP=Y3=14.0 , π3=0% , r3=2.0% , i3=2.0%.

👀 Reading hidden code
165 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
201 μs

Exercise 12. Stuck in deflation (not covered in classes)

👀 Reading hidden code
157 μs

Consider an economy that, for some reason, finds itself in an equilibrium inside the ZLB zone, as in point 1zl in the figure below. Suppose there are no more shocks on the demand or supply sides.

👉 a) Is 1ZL an equilibrium point for this economy?

👀 Reading hidden code
223 μs

self_correction8 =0.0

👀 Reading hidden code
845 μs
1zl2zl1313.213.413.613.81414.214.4−5−4−3−2−10
ASAS2ADzlZLBYpEq1Eq2Stuck in deflationGDP trillion dollars (Y)Rate of inflation (% points)
👀 Reading hidden code
63.5 ms

Answer (a)

The point 1zl is a short-term equilibrium for this economy, with Y=13.4 trillion dollars and π=2%.

👀 Reading hidden code
184 μs

👉 b) Using the slider self_correction8 and the figure below, show the long-term equilibrium in this economy.

👀 Reading hidden code
184 μs

Answer (b)

At point 1zl the economy is in a deep recession: Y<YP, which will force inflation to decrease. If inflation goes down, this will be represented by the AS curve shifting downwards (or to the right). This shift will only stop when the AS curve crosses the ADzl curve at point 2zl. This point represents the long-term equilibrium in this economy.

👀 Reading hidden code
146 μs

👉 c) Can you propose one policy measure to help this economy escape the deflation trap at point 2zl?

👀 Reading hidden code
216 μs

Answer (c)

The only policy measures that can force the economy to move out of the ZLB are either (i) a large increase in public spending (an increase in G), or (ii) a large reduction in nominal interest rates (i), so that aggregate demand will increase so much that the new AD curve will cross the AS curve above the ZLB.

👀 Reading hidden code
148 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
170 μs

Exercise 13. Secular stagnation (not covered in classes)

👀 Reading hidden code
156 μs

Consider that initially, the economy is at point 1 in the figure below but suffers a huge negative external shock on aggregate demand: ΔA=0.5 trillion dollars. The impact of this shock can be seen in the movement of the economy to point 2 below. If the economy is at point 2, what will happen to it over time? Answer this question by maniputaing the slider self_correction9 below.

👀 Reading hidden code
197 μs

ΔĀ9 =-0.5

self_correction9 =0.0

👀 Reading hidden code
5.3 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
31.1 ms
1231313.213.413.613.81414.2−3−2−10123
AS2YpADADzlZLBASEq1Eq2Eq3Secular stagnationGDP trillion dollars (Y)Rate of inflation (% points)
👀 Reading hidden code
28.5 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
8.4 μs

Answer

The AD negative shock drove the economy from point 1 to point 2. The economy is in a large recession because GDP (13.472 trillion dollars) is much smaller than Potential GDP (14 trillion dollars).

How will the economy move out of this big recession? By the self-correcting mechanism, inflation will have to come down because we are in a recession. Therefore, the AS curve will move down but has to stop when it reaches the kink of the AD curve. This is point 3 in the figure above. The reason for the AS curve to stop at the kink is simple: if firms supply more goods & services than 13.472 trillion dollars, there will be no demand for them, so they must stop the aggregate production level at point 3.

The literature describes this situation as the "secular stagnation" case. The term "secular" represents "for a long period". The only way out of this problem is if the government significantly increases public spending or the central bank implements unconventional monetary policy (remember, at the ZLB, the nominal interest rate is already 0%). Obviously, if a sizeable positive shock occurs (in the AD or the AS functions), the economy may also be able to return to the level of potential GDP. However, it is better to have public institutions acting than expecting some luck from unknown and uncertain exogenous forces.

👀 Reading hidden code
235 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
128 μs

Exercise 14. Deflation trap: the good & the bad equilibrium ⛔

👀 Reading hidden code
141 μs

Note

This exercise is a complex one (it is hard to solve). For this reason, it is not compulsory. Read this exercise only if you like macroeconomics a lot and want to move to a more demanding level in this field.

👀 Reading hidden code
131 μs

Consider the data from Exercise 10. However, due to the falling oil prices in international markets, supply suffers a positive shock of Δρ=2.0. Simultaneously, inflation expectations fall by 2 percentage points; the new value for inflation expectations is πe=0%. These impacts can be seen in the figure below. What will happen to the economy if there is no active fiscal policy?

👀 Reading hidden code
207 μs
ρ6 = -2.0 ; πᵉ6 = 0.0;
👀 Reading hidden code
11.7 μs
122zl31313.51414.515−6−4−202468
ASASADADzlZLBYpEq1Eq2Eq2zlEq3Deflation trap: the good & the bad equilibriumGDP trillion dollars (Y)Rate of inflation (% points)
👀 Reading hidden code
33.9 ms

Answer

A positive supply shock of -2 (ρ=2.0), with a simultaneous decline in inflation expectations by 2 percentage points (πe=0%), moved the economy out of point 1. The economy will end up either in point 2 or in point 2zl. The economic fundamentals are still there: (i) there is a new AS curve that supplies a certain level of goods & services at a lower level of inflation than before those two events occurred; (ii) the AD curve is the same as before. Why do we have two different short-term macroeconomic equilibria? Because people may behave in strange ways, not easily explained by the "economic fundamentals".

Suppose most people believe that the two exogenous factors will cause the economy to fall into a significant recession and deflation. In that case, these self-fulfilling prophecies will force the economy to move to point 2zl. At this point, the economy is in recession, and by the market self-correcting mechanism, inflation will have to come down, forcing the AS curve to move to the right until it reaches point 3. This point is a short-term and long-term equilibrium point, which means that the economy will deflate if nothing else happens. What may remove the economy from this situation if no other shock occurs? The usual tools culprits will do: a significant expansionary fiscal policy or a non-conventional monetary policy.

On the other hand, if most people are not too worried about the negative impact of those two factors, this attitude will positively affect economic activity, and the economy will jump into point 2. Notice that there is nothing wrong with having lower oil prices, nor with private agents formulating lower inflation expectations. What happens is that aggregate demand will increase if inflation goes down, as will GDP. Point 2 is a short-term equilibrium but not a long-term one. As we are in an economic boom, inflation will have to increase due to the market self-correcting mechanism, and the AS curve will move up until it reaches point 1. This point is both a short-run and a long-run macroeconomic equilibrium. In this case, we do not need an active fiscal policy to deal with the long-run disequilibrium in point 2. A conventional monetary policy has to accommodate the gradual increase in inflation while the economy moves from point 2 to point 1.

In macroeconomics, this situation of having the same economic fundamentals and two different long-term macroeconomic equilibria is normally denominated by "self-fulfilling prophecies", "sunspots", or "indeterminacy". As Isaac Newton once put it: "I can calculate the motion of heavenly bodies, but not the madness of people". The madness of people may prevail everywhere, even in macroeconomics.

👀 Reading hidden code
290 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
120 μs

Exercise 15. The trouble with inflation (optional)

👀 Reading hidden code
147 μs

The figure below shows the main contributors to inflation in October 2022 in the USA. The inflation rate for all items was 0.4% between October and September 2022. This monthly inflation rate would correspond to annual inflation of 4.9% if the same 0.4% were verified in all following months ((1+0.004)121=0.049). In September, the monthly inflation rate between August and September 2022 was 0.6%, leading to an annual inflation rate of 7.44%.

👉 a) If this trend continues over time, what does it tell us about the behavior of inflation?

👀 Reading hidden code
212 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
31.1 μs

Answer (a)

If that trend continues, it tells us that inflation was coming down (annually) in that period.

👀 Reading hidden code
150 μs

👉 b) Looking at the various items in the figure below, what items mainly contributed to the inflation rate in October 2022?

👀 Reading hidden code
171 μs

Answer (b)

The two main items that displayed a huge price increase in October were Fuel oil and Gasoline (all types). Fuel oil will affect transportation costs because almost all shipping consumes this fuel. Gasoline is the most significant energy used by everyday transportation, affecting all aspects of life.

So, if the prices of these two types of combustion items were going down to acceptable levels, overall inflation would also go down. The problem is that these prices are set in international markets, and it is unclear what individual economies can do about it.

👀 Reading hidden code
166 μs

👉 c) Can the Fed do anything to control the prices of those items most responsible for the October inflation?

👀 Reading hidden code
161 μs

Answer (c)

No, the Fed can do very little to influence the increase in Gasoline and Fuel oil prices. The Fed can reduce aggregate demand by increasing nominal interest rates and, by doing so, can reduce the demand for those items. However, the prices of oil are highly determined by a cartel (OPEC+). Therefore, the power of the Fed is quite limited in this case.

👀 Reading hidden code
180 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
139 μs

Exercise 16. New Taylor Rule: more emphasis on the output-gap

👀 Reading hidden code
162 μs

In exercise 5, we dealt with the original Taylor rule. Various economists have suggested that the original Taylor rule gives too little weight to the output gap. The (New) Taylor Rule puts a higher weight on that gap, and we will see that it performs much better than the original one. The curve has the same expression, with the only difference that now we will have (λπ=0.5, λy=1.0).

👀 Reading hidden code
249 μs
Taylor_new = r̄ .+ π .+ λ_π .* (π .- πᵀ) .+ (λ_y .+ Δλ_y) .* (100 .* ((Y .- Yᴾ) ./ Yᴾ));
👀 Reading hidden code
185 ms

Note

The slider below Δλ_y=0.5 tells us that the central bank is more concerned about the output-gap than in the original version of the rule (where λ_y=0.5 and Δλ_y=0). See what happens by changing the value of this slider.

👀 Reading hidden code
165 μs

👉 a) Despite performing better that the original Taylor rule, what happens when extreme events knock on ecoonomic activity? Like, for example, the Great Recession of 2008-2010, the Covid pandemic in 2020, or the recent rampant inflation in 2022/20223?

👀 Reading hidden code
171 μs

Δλ_y =0.5

👀 Reading hidden code
879 μs
1960197019801990200020102020−5051015201960197019801990200020102020−10−5051015
New Taylor RuleFFRNew Taylor rule versus the Federal Funds RateNew Taylor rule minus the Federal Funds Rate
👀 Reading hidden code
424 μs

Answer (a)

This New Taylor rule continues to perform poorly in the face of extreme economic events. At the bottom of the Great Recession (July 2009), it suggests that the FFR should have been negative at 6.9%, it should have been 9.17% at the trough of Covid (June 2020), and at +12.3% on July 2022.

These rates are impossible to justify from an economic and financial point of view.

👀 Reading hidden code
233 μs

👉 b) Given the evidence in these three rules, are monetary policy rules useless?

👀 Reading hidden code
168 μs

Answer (b)

  1. Rules are rules; they should be used with knowledge and wisdom. Without them, a central bank may look like a ship in the open ocean without a destination. However, applying them literally shows a total lack of wisdom and prudence. The economy may be confronted by a wide range of shocks, some of which are extremely difficult to deal with given their impacts and nature.

  2. Some rules perform poorly, but others perform very well (as seen in Exercise 6). So, if central banks base their decisions on rules that perform very well, they will make smaller mistakes than if they use bad or no rules.

  3. But remember: no rule can accommodate all shocks that may potentially hit the economy, and no rule can work well in the face of extraordinary shocks like COVID-19 or a major war. Extraordinary shocks require extraordinary measures by central banks, and no rule can fully consider the contingencies that may arise from such situations.

👀 Reading hidden code
223 μs

Reality Check

👀 Reading hidden code
151 μs

Application 1

An important speech by Jerome Powell, Fed's Chair

👀 Reading hidden code
184 μs

Jerome Powel (2020) in a speech at the Conference “Navigating the Decade Ahead: Implications for Monetary Policy,” symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, August 27, 2020, with the title "New Economic Challenges and the Fed’s Monetary Policy Review" mentioned the following:

"Inflation that runs below its desired level can lead to an unwelcome fall in longer-term inflation expectations, which, in turn, can pull actual inflation even lower, resulting in an adverse cycle of ever-lower inflation and inflation expectation.

This dynamic is a problem because expected inflation feeds directly into the general level of interest rates. Well-anchored inflation expectations are critical for giving the Fed the latitude to support employment when necessary without destabilizing inflation. But if inflation expectations fall below our 2 percent objective, interest rates would decline in tandem. In turn, we would have less scope to cut interest rates to boost employment during an economic downturn, further diminishing our capacity to stabilize the economy through cutting interest rates. We have seen this adverse dynamic play out in other major economies around the world and have learned that once it sets in, it can be very difficult to overcome. We want to do what we can to prevent such a dynamic from happening here.” (page 8/9)

Do you see any connection between what we discussed this week and the great concerns of the President (Chair) of the Federal Reserve Board of the USA in his most relevant speech in 2020? Do you think the problems of deflation and lower inflation expectations are irrelevant issues in modern macroeconomics?

👀 Reading hidden code
485 μs

Hint

This speech touches on all major points covered this week: the fear of deflation, the importance of inflation expectations, the relevance of having a 2% target interest rate, and a responsible central should do all it takes to prevent deflation from setting in.

👀 Reading hidden code
147 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
141 μs

Application 2

Ignore Japan at your peril

👀 Reading hidden code
181 μs
19911994199720002003200620092012201520182021−20246
URCPIInflation (CPI) and Unemployment (UR) Rates in Japan: 1991-2021Monthly observationsPercentage points1998-M07Shinzo Abe as prime-minister
👀 Reading hidden code
69.0 ms

It is incredible how a developed, democratic, and open society fell into the deflation trap in the late 1990s, even though successive governments and central bank presidents tried to avoid such a situation. The central bank of Japan has an inflation target of 2%, like most developed economies. However, from mid-1998 until 2021, Japan could only achieve such a target in 12 out of the 264 months. In fact, most of the time, Japan has experienced quite severe deflation (-1%, -2%, and even -2.5%), some of them for extended periods. Surprisingly, despite significant deflation, the Japanese economy has displayed relatively low unemployment rates.

Can we explain this Japanese case using our model? And with our exercises above? Yes, from Exercise 8 onwards we can easily explain the Japanese case. Why has Japan not been able to escape from the long-term equilibrium inside the ZLB? Some influential economists had argued that in the past – before 2013, when Prime Minister Shinzo Abe came to power and nominated a new Governor of the Central Bank of Japan – Japanese governments and the central bank did not take the necessary measures to avoid the economy diving into the deflationary trap. They only took timid measures to deal with an exceptional danger, and the trap settled in. The positive impact on inflation of the measures taken by Prime Minister Shinzo Abe and his appointed Bank of Japan Governor (Haruhiko Kuroda) after 2013 can be easily seen in the figure above. Since 2013, the number of months with positive inflation has been much greater than those with deflation, which is a very different picture from what had happened before.

👀 Reading hidden code
427 μs

👀 Reading hidden code
141 μs

Auxiliary cells (do not delete)

👀 Reading hidden code
215 μs
TableOfContents()
👀 Reading hidden code
7.7 μs
Data files used in this notebook
  • NBER_Recessions.csv

  • UR_FFR.csv

  • EZ_inflation.csv

  • Taylor.csv

  • FFRCPIOil.csv

  • Scary_Paper.csv

  • JapanDeflationV1.csv

These CSV files must be kept in the same folder as this notebook.

👀 Reading hidden code
8.7 ms

CSS code

👀 Reading hidden code
156 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
2.8 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
5.9 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
373 ms

Exercise 2. Supporting cells (Unemployment and recessions)

👀 Reading hidden code
158 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
3.2 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
11.6 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
1.1 ms

Exercise 3. Supporting cells (Inflation targetting)

👀 Reading hidden code
162 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
1.9 s
👀 Reading hidden code
13.8 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
383 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
46.2 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
195 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
127 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
347 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
172 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
105 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
109 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
42.7 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
314 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
261 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
260 μs

Exercise 4+5+6+16. Supporting cells (Taylor rule)

👀 Reading hidden code
359 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
14.4 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
8.5 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
33.7 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
9.4 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
11.2 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
9.4 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
31.9 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
86.4 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
26.9 μs

Exercise 7. Supporting cells (Volcker disinflation)

👀 Reading hidden code
155 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
940 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
19.4 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
24.6 μs

Exercise 4. Supporting cells (Scary paper)

👀 Reading hidden code
156 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
5.1 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
14.5 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
62.7 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
83.4 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
634 μs

Exercise 9. Supporting cells (Abenomics)

👀 Reading hidden code
222 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
9.6 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
3.0 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
14.9 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
9.3 μs

Exercise 10. Supporting cells (ZLB)

👀 Reading hidden code
160 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
23.4 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
19.9 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
280 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
46.1 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
34.5 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
219 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
9.7 ms

Exercise 11. Supporting cells (Negative demand shock)

👀 Reading hidden code
221 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
37.2 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
845 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
140 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
58.3 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
503 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
501 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
446 μs

Exercise 13. Supporting cells (secular stagnation)

👀 Reading hidden code
156 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
35.4 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
15.0 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
796 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
140 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
184 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
7.7 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
202 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
739 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
150 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
183 μs

Exercise 14. Supporting cells (Deflation trap)

👀 Reading hidden code
156 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
153 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
184 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
251 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
198 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
212 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
150 ms
👀 Reading hidden code
67.0 μs
👀 Reading hidden code
180 μs